This blog will examine most of the inequities involving the law, immigrations, education, employment, political, health care. It will showcase current news events concerning US and world economic, Middle-eastern revolt issues while trying to explain and resolve those issues.
Showing posts with label Book Of The Day. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Book Of The Day. Show all posts
Keep in mind that this book was published on
10/16/11, one month before Beck admitted complete ignorance "with the
economy." Chapter 1 is entitled "Ancient History, Modern
Lessons," and that misrepresents the overall subject of the first chapter
which is how past empires can serve as a warning to our current status as the
world's remaining superpower and hegemonic state.
This isn’t exactly a new theme for an
American economic calamity for several years. The irony is that his “Plan”
now places the blame for our dilemma on the American people. Once you see what
we’re really up against, it’s much easier to develop a realistic plan. To fix
ourselves financially, Glenn argues, we have to fix ourselves first.
That means some serious introspection and, ultimately, a series of actions that
will unite all Americans around the concept of shared sacrifice.
We are the problem. And to fix it
Beck has suddenly adopted the notion of shared sacrifice, a concept he
previously regarded as abhorrent and a product of the socialistic ideology that
he believes diminishes individual freedom and responsibility. Furthermore, his
own philosophy is one that advocates allowing our economic system to crash and burn. Again, a concept he previously reviled as the Cloward/Piven strategy. He
asserts that we are beyond the point of no return and must abandon all measures
to stimulate growth and create jobs. Let the bottom fall out, cower in your
bunker with your Survival Seeds and gold coins. Cling to your God and guns and,
if your faith is strong enough, you will be redeemed by some miracle from
above.
Our nation is financially broke, but that’s
just a side effect of our broken spirit, our broken faith in government, the
broken promises by our leaders, and a broken political system that has
centralized power at the expense of individual rights. How did we get into this
mess? Glenn Beck thinks the answer
is pretty simple: Because we’ve turned our backs on the Constitution.
Few of us have ever seen the whole picture,
and politicians have done everything in their power to hide the truth. Brokeexposes
what we’re really facing—and how to fix it. Packed with great stories from
history, invaluable teachable moments, and Glenn Beck’s trademark combination of entertainment and enlightenment, Brokemakes the
case that when you’re traveling in the wrong direction, slight course
corrections won’t cut it—you need to take drastic action. Through a return to
individual rights, an uncompromising adherence to the Constitution, and a
complete rethinking about the role of government in a free society, Glenn exposes
the idea of “transformation” for the progressive smokescreen that it is, and
instead builds a compelling case that restoration is the only way forward. With
this awareness, it’s much easier to develop a realistic plan for uniting all
Americans around the concept of shared sacrifice. After all, this generation
may not be asked to storm beaches, but we are being asked to do something just
as critical to preserving freedom.
Visionaries Pierre Lemieux and William Bonner invite readers to re-examine long accepted notions of what America is and what it means to be an American. Lemieux and Bonner carefully chose each of the written works included in the striking anthology to spark imagination, thought, and debate.
Each of the selections some well-known classics and others the thoughts of less conventional thinkers--builds on the next, engaging readers in an exploration of the concepts that are fundamental to our view of who we are. No stone is left unturned as subjects ranging from individual liberty to religion and self reliance are covered through the words of some of the most creative thinkers ever to put pen to paper. This arresting collection contains one of the most unique mixes of works ever to be compiled. From the documents that gave birth to America--the Declaration of Independence and the Bill of Rights--to the insightful reflections from the always delightful H.L. Mencken on the American character and Ralph Waldo Emerson's classic words on individual and religious self reliance. The Idea of America is a true celebration of the spirit that is America.
Margaret Thatcher, the Conservative prime
minister who dismantled Britain's socialist economy in the 1980s, once noted
that "there can be no liberty without economic liberty."
In Thatcher's opinion, the
freedom to employ one's resources as one sees fit is the hallmark of all other
political rights. While Thatcher's observation is quite correct, it no doubt
benefited from hindsight. By the 1980s, Thatcher had experienced the very real
difficulties presented to freedom and prosperity in her efforts to dismantle
Britain's cumbersome welfare state. Moreover, she had begun to see the
crumbling of the socialist system in neighboring countries such as France and
the Soviet Union.
F.A. Hayek
Some forty years earlier,
however, before the United Kingdom implemented its vast system of planning,
another Briton named F.A. Hayek made a similar point in his acclaimed treatise,
"The Road to Serfdom." In the book, Hayek connects the concept of a planned
economy with the Nazi rise to power in Germany in the 1930s. "The rise of
fascism and Nazism," writes Hayek, "was not a reaction against the
socialist trends of the proceeding period but a necessary outcome of those
tendencies." Writing in 1944, at a time when
many Americas and Britons feared Hitler's totalitarianism and simultaneously
supported a continuation of the wartime planning of the economy, Hayek
invariably tied the two concepts together. According to Hayek, a state that
assumes control over what is produced "would control what we consume
almost as effectively as if it directly told us how to spend our income." For Hayek, once economic
freedom is lost, all other freedoms are soon to follow. In fact, "The Road to Serfdom" paints a clear picture of how even tentative steps towards
socialism inevitably lead to totalitarianism. Socialism, says Hayek,
exchanges society's supreme ideal of freedom for the vague concept of
"fairness." But by focusing on fairness, society slowly abandons its
respect for the rule of law. What is "fair" is determined by judges
and the state and may very well conflict with an individual's right to
property, prosperity, or political freedom. In other words, once a state can
control competition, redistribute wealth, or plan aspects of the economy, it
becomes the ultimate arbiter of right and wrong. Hayek also points out that a
democratic government cannot salvage freedom in a socialist system, despite the
passionate arguments to the contrary on the left. Instead, notes Hayek, democracy
must ultimately succumb to absolute planners because the legislative branch of
democracy is simply unable to plan -- or decide what is fair for all of society
-- on a massive scale. Even defenders of socialism, notes Hayek, acknowledge
that an economic plan needs a unitary concept to be effective. "Planning
leads to dictatorship because dictatorship is the most effective instrument of
coercion and the enforcement of ideals and, as such, essential if central
planning on a large scale is to be possible." Even if a socialist government
were able to maintain democracy, however, Hayek points out that the system
would not necessarily preserve freedom. Unlike liberty, says Hayek, democracy
is not the highest political end. In Hayek's words democracy merely is a
"utilitarian device for safeguarding internal peace and individual
freedom. As such it is by no means infallible or certain." Such observations are worth
remembering as the United States eagerly promotes democracy around the world.
The Soviet Union, it is worth remembering, claimed to be the most democratic
nation on earth. While democracy is certainly a useful political system it does
not, by itself, create or protect liberty. As Hayek notes, economic freedom,
not democracy alone, is the ultimate protector of human freedom. Despite Hayek's passionate
defense of liberty, he does not advocate an extreme laissez-faire approach to
economic affairs. Hayek recognizes that some aspects of the economy and human
interaction cannot be effectively resolved through competition. In these
situations, Hayek advocates government intervention to address market failures.
In a notable departure from classical liberalism or today's libertarianism,
Hayek defends regulating poisonous substances or working hours as long as the
measures are consistently and generally applied. While this position of limited
government intervention provides some insight into Hayek's personal views of
the appropriate place for government, "The Road to Serfdom" is
largely a reactionary work. Hayek vigorously attacks planning and
totalitarianism, but he generally avoids stating his own position of
government's place in the economy. In some respects, of course,
the absence of Hayek's own views highlights the importance and urgency of what
he did say -- namely, that the continuation of wartime planning in America and
Britain would lead to totalitarianism. In this light it is conceivable that
Hayek did not want to distract the reader from his warning by introducing his
own views into the argument. Still, Hayek's consistent focus on one topic and
the negative tone of his writing makes the book somewhat repetitive. In fact, for today's
post-Reagan era readers, the more subtle remarks of Hayek's work may have the
most impact. Hayek warns, for instance, against the leftist practice of
vilifying capitalism by pointing to the negative aspects of the system such as
unemployment or inequality. "It is essential," he writes, "that
we should re-learn frankly to face the fact that freedom can be had only at a
price and that as individuals we must be prepared to make severe material
sacrifices to preserve our liberty." Freedom, not government, has
allowed Americans to achieve unmatched prosperity. By limiting government and
relying on individual initiative, the United States has created a better
society for all. Hayek's "Road to Serfdom," however, reminds us that
freedom is a privilege that must always be safeguarded, not only from external
forces, but also from ourselves. Freedom is too precious to be taken for
granted.
What
makes countries end up in persistent and permanent poverty? Why is Mexico much
poorer than the United States? Why is Latin America so fundamentally different
to North America? How is it possible that an average American is 40 times
richer than an average Sierra Leonean? Is it climate, geography, culture, or
could it be the ignorance of domestic leaders?
Acemoglu and Robinson suggest
it’s none of these – rather, the real reason behind the poverty trap and
significant between-nation differences lies in the role of political and
economic institutions. Politics and the formation of political institutions
take centre stage in their book, which formulates the thesis that only within
an inclusive political system is it possible for nations to achieve prosperity.
The opposite scenario will occur under extractive political institutions where
wealth will be accumulated within a narrow ruling elite which will aim to
preserve its power thus sentencing a nation to persistent poverty.
In the very beginning of the book the
authors hint to the reader how it will be organized – through a series of
historical case studies upon which they illustrate their theory of institutional
change and the consequential success or failure of nations. It starts with the
example of Nogales, a city on the US-Mexican border, which is split in half by
a fence. One city, in the same geographical position, characterized by the same
cultural upbringings, same population, same diseases, but one part three times
richer, much healthier, safer, and with higher living standards. The crucial
difference is the very border separating the two parts of the city depicting
the different institutional settings within them.
North and South Korea; Can you see the Difference?
The authors make a strong claim that
this great divergence on a localized level had its roots in the very start of
colonization of North and South America. As the Spaniards came to the Aztec,
Mayan and Inca empires they had a single aim of conquering the indigenous
population and extracting their wealth. By founding their settlements the
colonizers designed a system that would coerce the indigenous people to work
for them and extract resources while enriching only the small ruling Spanish elite.
This made the Spanish Crown quite rich at the time, as massive amounts of gold
and other resources flooded into the country.
The colonization strategy of the English
was the same as of the Spaniards – extract the resources and force the
indigenous population to work for the colonial elite, which would, along with
the Crown, obtain maximum benefits from it. This strategy worked well in India
and Africa, but it failed in North America. First of all, they were late. North
America was less attractive and much scarcer in gold than South America. In
addition, the Native Americans put up far greater resistance and more
importantly didn’t allow themselves to become enslaved and forced into manual
labour for the newcomers.
Daron Acemoglu
It was up to the settlers to work themselves. At
first they were coerced into working by the colony’s rulers but this strategy failed due to a range of possibilities for the coerced to escape to the
Indians. As a result, the colony needed to create different institutions to
create incentives for the settlers. With more personal freedom came demands for
more political freedom. In fact, the authors claim that the historical prelude
to the monumental 1774 US Constitution and the colonists’ fight for liberty was
the formation of the General Assembly in colonial Jamestown in 1619.
These initial institutional
differences manifested through the limitation of political power, democratic
principles, and economic incentives that paved the different development paths
of US and Mexico, generating the crucial difference between the two parts of
the city of Nogales.
An intriguing case study approach
analyzed through the lens of institutional formation is the framework used
throughout the book. The emphasis is on how inclusive political institutions
can lead to inclusive economic institutions which will lay the foundations of
wealth creation and sustainable growth. The combination of inclusive political
and economic institutions shapes the incentives needed for a society to
prosper. If people have their wealth expropriated, they will lack the
incentives to create or sustain it. They will fail to innovate and fail to
achieve progress. People need an initial set of institutions to reduce
uncertainty and maintain stability.
The two examples exists side-by-side
This initial set of inclusive economic
institutions includes secure property rights, rule of law, public services and
freedom to contract. The state is relied upon to provide all of these. It is
the role of the state to impose law and order, enforce contracts and prevent
theft and fraud. When the state fails to provide such a set of institutions it
becomes extractive, where its main objective is to satisfy a small powerful
elite (whether the ruler of the country, a set of rulers or prevalent interest
groups).
Acemoglu and Robinson formulate their
central hypothesis around the fact that a strong set of economic institutions
which will guide incentives towards creating wealth can only be achieved
through more political freedom. Political inclusiveness and the distribution of
political power within a society are the key elements that will determine the
success or the failure of nations.
The outcome of this insightful thesis
originating from the works of Adam Smith can often depend on random historical
events. They refer to these as the critical junctures of history that exploited
the initial small institutional differences and led to diverging development
paths of nations. One interesting example of a critical juncture that probably
contributed to the divergence between Western and Eastern Europe was the
bubonic plague, better known as the Black Death, in the 14th century. Another
example is the aforementioned different colonization pattern in many countries,
the most notable one being between North and South America.
In their pursuit of an explanation for
the role of politics in development, the authors touch upon other dominant
theories that have tried to explain poor growth and under-development. They
stress three approaches: (1) the geographical position of the country
(countries in the sub-tropical area), which blames exposure to rough climate,
barren land and tropical diseases; (2) the cultural attribute, where the
population is to be blamed for not being hard-working (less productive) due to
their ethical, religious or cultural boundaries (a famous example here is Max
Weber’s Protestant ethic argument); and (3) the ignorance of the country’s
ruling elites, implying that if they had better economic advice, they would be
able to emerge from poverty. They also touch upon the dual economy paradigm that
blamed African underdevelopment on the co-existence of two sectors within an
economy between which social mobility was almost impossible.
Each of these arguments is found faulty
by the authors. The rule of a narrow elite that organizes the society for its
own rent-extracting interest is a common trajectory every nation followed on
its road to poverty. The differences between the two parts of Nogales, two
Koreas, or East and West Germany cannot be explained by geography, culture,
diseases or ignorance – it could only be explained by a different set of
political institutions that resulted in different economic outcomes. As for the
African dual economy paradigm, the dual economy was artificially created by the
ruling (white) elite that maintained extractive political institutions.
The problem isn’t that poor nations
remain poor because of outside (or inside) exploitation, economic ignorance or
laziness of the population. It lies in the role of politics, and how the ruling
elite will organize the country’s political and economic institutions. If
political institutions are organized as extractive and concentrated in the
hands of a narrow elite, then economic institutions will only serve the purpose
of the ruling elites extracting the maximum wealth for themselves. If they are
organized as inclusive, power being dispersed among the many rather than
concentrated among the few, then this institutional environment will create
incentives of inclusive economic institutions, where innovation and creative
destruction will ensure the creation of sustainable economic growth and
development. Becoming a rich nation necessitates the overthrow of the ruling
elites and the distribution of power and political rights evenly within a
society. The government has to become accountable and responsive to its people,
who can then use this security and stability to advance on the economic
opportunities available to them.
However, the authors do admit that
growth can be achieved within a set of extractive political institutions. The
elites can simply reallocate resources into temporary highly productive
activities under their control (e.g. from agriculture to industry). But the
problem is that this growth is unsustainable in the long run. When the economy
runs out of steam, so will rapid growth and the country will first be exposed
to an economic and ultimately to a political crisis. The example of the rapid
growth of Soviet Russia illustrates this point. It wasn’t driven by innovation,
but state control and when the foundations for growth were exhausted, nothing
came to replace it. The authors predict the same thing happening to China. Even
though China is different than Soviet Russia, as it deploys some inclusive
economic institutions, the political elites still constrain creative destruction.
They mention the example of a Chinese entrepreneur who wanted to compete with
big, inefficient state-owned steel companies and ended up in prison as a
result.
The Chinese anti-entrepreneurship climate, censorship of the media, and
technological growth based on adoption of technologies rather than innovation
are all signals of an extractive political system in which growth is not
sustainable. China can overcome this and reach sustainable growth if it manages
to undergo a political reform that will introduce more individual and political
freedom. Until then, they are destined to repeat the Soviet scenario.
The book develops as a fascinating
storyline comprising of a multitude of vivid historical examples that support
the central thesis of the authors. After identifying the main framework of the
analysis in the first four chapters, it takes the reader on a journey through
history featuring a number of famous historical and more recent stories of
success and failure. This gives the reader an opportunity to see how politics
can indeed play an important part in the development of a society.
We see the same historical pattern
reoccurring in Venice and Ancient Rome, in Ethiopia and Mayan city-states, in
Soviet Russia and Congo, in 18th century Spain, absolutist Austro-Hungary or
tsarist Russia. The common characteristic that led them to failure was the
extractiveness of their political institutions. Even if they did briefly
experience rapid growth (such as the absolutist monarchies or Soviet Russia),
this growth was temporary and unsustainable, unless a path towards
inclusiveness followed. When Ancient Rome, Venice and the Mayan city-states had
even partially inclusive institutions that offered the proper incentives for
growth, they managed to experience it. However, when they switched to
authoritarianism andusurpation of power by the elites, conflicts emerged and the
downfall of their societies began. Inclusiveness was replaced by extractiveness
and consequently development was reversed.
In England, something different
happened. Whilst in other countries repression was the dominant type of social
order, in England the demand for more property rights and a greater political
voice set the stage for sustained growth and prosperity.
Creative destruction and technological
innovation made people richer, led to a new distribution of wealth, and more
importantly new distribution of power in the society. The elites, afraid of
losing their privileges, opposed this process. They felt threatened and formed
barriers to innovation. But in England, through political conflict, the rising
wealth of merchants and manufactures was able to overcome this opposition and
constrain the power of the sovereign, initiating the beginning of a new
historical era.
This is precisely why the Industrial
Revolution started in England, not anywhere else in the World. The Industrial
Revolution developed on the trails of the Glorious Revolution. It was the
importance of a broad coalition representing the people that succeeded. If
there had not been such a broad coalition, one elite would have simply
overtaken the other and continued with extractive institutions (as happened
briefly during the dictatorship of Oliver Cromwell). Irreversible political
change and the switch to inclusiveness transformed the economic incentives in
the society and created enormous wealth and prosperity.
But not all countries followed this
rapid development and not all countries embraced the benefits of the Industrial
Revolution, some even for a long time. It is due to these defining moments of
history (critical junctures) where the authors explain why all those countries
that developed on the ruins of the Ottoman Empire tend to be relatively
impoverished (provided that they are not oil exporters). The Ottoman Empire,
instead of embracing change, felt threatened by it and sentenced its minions to
another 200 years of extraction and poverty. The opposition to the elites in
the Ottoman Empire never grew as strong as it did in England, which is why
inclusive institutions never developed there. The same is true for a multitude
of countries at the time, including Spain, Austro/Hungary, Russia or China.
Wherever those with political power felt
threatened by technology and innovation, they prevented it, and by doing so
they effectively prevented wealth creation and prosperity.
The summing-up of their analysis is
through explaining the vicious and the virtuous cycles of prosperity. Whenever
inclusive institutions are present, the virtuous cycle will create positive
feedback loops that will prevent the elites overcoming them. It will make sure
that inclusive institutions expand and become persistent. Similarly, in the
case of extractive institutions vicious cycles will generate negative feedback
loops that will prevent progress.
In order for the virtuous cycle to work
the first precondition is to have pluralism, which will constitute the rule of
law and lead to more inclusive economic institutions. Inclusive economic
institutions will remove the need for extraction since those in power will gain
little but lose a lot if engaged in a repression and constraining democracy.
Finally, they also recognize the importance of free media to provide
information on threats against inclusive institutions.
The virtuous cycle explains how the
reforms of the political system in England or the US became irreversible, since
those in power understood that any possible deviation would endanger their own
position. The examples of British consolidation and its slow, contingent path
to democracy in which the people gradually demanded and gradually received more
rights; or the trust-busting in the US in the beginning of the 20th century; or
the failed attempts of President Roosevelt to limit the power of the US Supreme
Court illustrate this point.
Pluralism and the rule of law were
critical conditions leading to the limits of political power that made the
virtuous cycle possible in the US and Britain. And this was precisely why
Fujimori’s Peru, Chavez’s Venezuela or Peron’s Argentina failed. They failed to
create institutions to limit political power.
These systems developed
extractive institutions and generated a vicious cycle in which the ruling elite
had no constraints on power and had great incentives for expropriation and
wealth extraction. Even if this elite were to be overthrown by a revolution,
the “iron law of oligarchy” implied that a new elite would simple replace the
old one and continue in its extraction, sometimes even worse than under the old
elite. This is why the authors are somewhat sceptical of the ability of the
Arab Spring to produce the necessary shift towards inclusiveness.
Once again the authors convince the
reader in the mechanism of the negative feedback loop and the iron law of
oligarchy through a multitude of cases ranging from Sierra Leone, Guatemala,
Ethiopia, Zimbabwe, Uzbekistan, Columbia, Argentina, Egypt and even slavery in
the US South. However, the vicious cycle in the US South was easier to break
due to the existence of inclusive institutions on the federal level. The Civil
Rights Movement generated equality in the South and paved the way for economic
growth.
Another good example of “breaking the
mould” is Botswana, where the natural resource course didn’t lead to extraction
from colonists or usurpation of power over who gets to control resource
extraction and enrich upon it. They have managed to seize their critical
juncture – postcolonial independence – and used it to develop inclusive
institutions.
The authors refrain from trying to write
a recipe for development since there is no such thing. Their theory based on
critical junctures and specific historical paths loses predictive power since it
is hard to tell which countries could break the mould anytime soon. The theory
can say which countries are likely to stay poor for a long time but it cannot
really answer the question on what will follow after events like the Arab
Spring. A range of factors will decide whether the Arab countries undergo a
gradual path towards inclusiveness or whether the iron rule of oligarchy prevails.
Finally, prosperity cannot be engineered
by international institutions with a recipe for reform or foreign aid; it has to
come from empowerment to the people and their inclusiveness in the political
process. Once a broad coalition is formed this will enable the inclusive
institutions to persist and the political reforms to become irreversible. One
can conclude that based on this approach, inclusive economic and political
institutions develop spontaneously, while extractive institutions are imposed
by outside coercion. The road to prosperity is thus always achieved through
more political, individual and economic freedom.
The only part the authors did not cover
in more detail is what happens after political and economic inclusiveness are
attained, when certain elites or organized interest groups try to obtain
political support to serve their own self-interest. An answer from the book
would probably be that this scenario falls out of the general definition of
inclusive political institutions, where the media is (partially) captured and
where narrow self-interests can curtail the system in order to extract certain
benefit. It is here that their framework could be extended, but the already
large scope and size of the book prevent the authors from engaging so deeply
into the subject.
The framework used in the book is based
on a rigorous fifteen-year research process conducted by the authors and
examined previously in some of their earlier, more analytical work. Regular
readers of their work will recognize many of the ideas on the consolidation of
democracies and political transitions coming from their 2006 book, Origins of
Dictatorships and Democracy, along with many academic articles. Why Nations
Fail builds on these findings thus providing the crowning achievement in their
political economy theory. It is a recommended read to all professions and
anyone interested in finding out why some nations are rich while others are
poor.
Even though the book lacks academic
rigour in supporting the theory and proving the causality of certain events and
their further manifestation, such virtues were probably not the authors’
objectives.
For anyone interested in the academic
proofs behind certain historical events, I recommend their earlier work in
which the analytical framework can be thoroughly analyzed. This book has
different goals. Its emphasis on historical case studies to make it more interesting
to the general reader succeeds in transferring the idea to all those outside
the economic and political science profession. They have managed to summarize
their theory and make the case for institutional change, while presenting it in
an understandable, yet brilliant way for all those who are not economists. That
alone marks the book as a success.
In his giantNew York Times bestseller, America Alone:
The End of the World as We Know It, Mark Steyn
predicted collapse for the rest of the Western World. Now, he adds, America has
caught up with Europe on the great rush to self-destruction.
It’s not just our looming financial collapse; it’s
not just a culture that seems on a fast track to perdition, full of hapless,
indulgent, childish people who think government has the answer for every
problem; it’s not just America’s potential eclipse as a world power because of
the drunken sailor policymaking in Washington—no, it’s all this and more that
spells one word for America: Armageddon.
With his trademark wit, Steyn delivers the
depressing news with raw and unblinking honesty—but also with the touch of vaudeville
stand-up and soft shoe that makes him the most entertaining, yet profound,
columnist on the planet. And as an immigrant with nowhere else to go, he offers
his own prescription for winning Americaback from the feckless and arrogant
liberal establishment that has done its level best to suffocate the world’s
last best hope in a miasma of debt, decay, and debility. You will not read a
more important—or more alarming, or even funnier—book all year thanAfter America.
In his
memoir, Barack Obama omits the full name of his mentor, simply calling him
“Frank.” Now, the truth is out: Never has a figure as deeply troubling and
controversial as Frank Marshall Davis had such an impact on the development of
an American president.
Although other radical influences on Obama, from Jeremiah Wright
to Bill Ayers, have been scrutinized, the public knows little about Davis, a
card-carrying member of the Communist Party USA, cited by the Associated Press
as an “important influence” on Obama, one whom he “looked to” not merely for
“advice on living” but as a “father” figure. While the Left has willingly dismissed Davis (with good reason), here are the indisputable, eye-opening facts: Frank Marshall Davis was a pro-Soviet, pro–Red China communist. His Communist Party USA card number, revealed in FBI files, was CP #47544. He was a prototype of the loyal Soviet patriot, so radical that the FBI placed him on the federal government’s Security Index. In the early 1950s, Davis opposed U.S. attempts to slow Stalin and Mao. He favored Red Army takeovers of Central and Eastern Europe, and communist control in Korea and Vietnam. Dutifully serving the cause, he edited and wrote for communist newspapers in both Chicago and Honolulu, courting contributors who were Soviet agents. In the 1970s, amid this dangerous political theater, Frank Marshall Davis came into Barack Obama’s life. Aided by access to explosive declassified FBI files, Soviet
archives, and Davis’s original newspaper columns, Paul Kengor explores how
Obama sought out Davis and how Davis found in Obama an impressionable young
man, one susceptible to Davis’s worldview that opposed American policy and
traditional values while praising communist regimes. Kengor sees remnants of
this worldview in Obama’s early life and even, ultimately, his presidency.
Paul Kengor
Kengor charts with definitive accuracy the progression of Davis’s
communist ideas from Chicago to Hawaii. He explores how certain elements of the
Obama administration’s agenda reflect Davis’s columns advocating wealth
redistribution, government stimulus for “public works projects,”
taxpayer-funding of universal health care, and nationalizing General Motors.
Davis’s writings excoriated the “tentacles of big business,” blasted Wall
Street and “greedy” millionaires, lambasted GOP tax cuts that “spare the rich,”
attacked “excess profits” and oil companies, and perceived the Catholic Church
as an obstacle to his vision for the state—all the while echoing Davis’s often
repeated mantra for transformational and fundamental “change.”
And yet,The Communistis not unsympathetic to Davis, revealing him as something of a
victim, an African- American who suffered devastating racial persecution in the
Jim Crow era, steering this justly angered young man on a misguided political
track. That Davis supported violent and heartless communist regimes over his
own country is impossible to defend. That he was a source of inspiration to
President Barack Obama is impossible to ignore. Is Obama working to fulfill the dreams of Frank Marshall Davis?
That question has been impossible to answer, since Davis’s writings and
relationship with Obama have either been deliberately obscured or dismissed as
irrelevant. With Paul Kengor’sThe Communist,Americans can
finally weigh the evidence and decide for themselves.
There were hundreds of thousands of American communists like Frank
who agitated throughout the twentieth century. They chose the wrong side of
history, a horrendously bloody side that left a wake of more than 100 million corpses
from the streets of the Bolshevik Revolution to the base of the Berlin
Wall—double the combined dead of the century’s two world wars. And they never
apologized. Quite the contrary, they cursed their accusers for daring to charge
(correctly) that they were communists whose ideology threatened the American
way and the greater world and all of humanity. They took their denials to the
grave, and still today their liberal/progressive dupes continue to conceal
their crimes and curse their accusers for them. We need hundreds and thousands
of more books on American communists like Frank, so we can finally start to get
this history right— and, more so, learn its vital lessons. To fail to do so is
a great historical injustice. We especially need to flesh out these lessons, which are morality
tales in the truest sense of the word, when we find the rarest case of a man
like “Frank” managing to influence someone as influential as the current
president of the United States of America—the leader of the free world and
driver of the mightiest political/economic engine in history. Such figures
cannot be ignored. The people who influence our presidents matter.